Powered by OpenAIRE graph
Found an issue? Give us feedback
image/svg+xml art designer at PLoS, modified by Wikipedia users Nina, Beao, JakobVoss, and AnonMoos Open Access logo, converted into svg, designed by PLoS. This version with transparent background. http://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:Open_Access_logo_PLoS_white.svg art designer at PLoS, modified by Wikipedia users Nina, Beao, JakobVoss, and AnonMoos http://www.plos.org/ Econometricaarrow_drop_down
image/svg+xml art designer at PLoS, modified by Wikipedia users Nina, Beao, JakobVoss, and AnonMoos Open Access logo, converted into svg, designed by PLoS. This version with transparent background. http://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:Open_Access_logo_PLoS_white.svg art designer at PLoS, modified by Wikipedia users Nina, Beao, JakobVoss, and AnonMoos http://www.plos.org/
Econometrica
Article
Data sources: UnpayWall
Econometrica
Article . 1989 . Peer-reviewed
Data sources: Crossref
versions View all 2 versions
addClaim

This Research product is the result of merged Research products in OpenAIRE.

You have already added 0 works in your ORCID record related to the merged Research product.

The Consumption-Based Capital Asset Pricing Model

Authors: Duffie, Darrell; Zame, William;

The Consumption-Based Capital Asset Pricing Model

Abstract

The paper provides conditions on the primitives of a continuous-time economy under which there exist equilibria obeying the Consumption-Based Capital Asset Pricing Model (CCAPM). The paper also extends the equilibrium characterization of interest rates of Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross (1985) to multi-agent economies. We do not use a Markovian state assumption. THIS WORK PROVIDES sufficient conditions on agents' primitives for the validity of the Consumption-Based Capital Asset Pricing Model (CCAPM) of Breeden (1979). As a necessary condition, Breeden showed that in a continuous-time equilibrium satisfying certain regularity conditions, one can characterize returns on securities as follows. The expected "instantaneous" rate of return on any security in excess of the riskless interest rate (the security's expected excess rate of return) is a multiple common to all securities of the "instantaneous covariance" of this excess return with aggregate consumption increments. This common multiple is the Arrow-Pratt measure of risk aversion of a representative agent. (Rubinstein (1976) published a discrete-time precursor of this result.) The exis- tence of equilibria satisfying Breeden's regularity conditions had been an open issue. We also show that the validity of the CCAPM does not depend on Breeden's assumption of Markov state information, and present a general asset pricing model extending the results of Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross (1985) as well as the discrete-time results of Rubinstein (1976) and Lucas (1978) to a multi-agent environment. Since the CCAPM was first proposed, much effort has been directed at finding sufficient conditions on the model primitives: the given assets, the agents' preferences, the agents' consumption endowments, and (in a production econ- omy) the feasible production sets. Conditions sufficient for the existence of continuous-time equilibria were shown in Duffie (1986), but the equilibria demonstrated were not shown to satisfy the additional regularity required for the CCAPM. In particular, Breeden assumed that all agents choose pointwise interior consumption rates, in order to characterize asset prices via the first order conditions of the Bellman equation. Interiority was also assumed by Huang (1987) in demonstrating a representative agent characterization of equilibrium, an approach exploited here. The use of dynamic programming and the Bellman equation, aside from the difficulty it imposes in verifying the existence of interior 1 Financial support from the National Science Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. We thank

  • BIP!
    Impact byBIP!
    citations
    This is an alternative to the "Influence" indicator, which also reflects the overall/total impact of an article in the research community at large, based on the underlying citation network (diachronically).
    131
    popularity
    This indicator reflects the "current" impact/attention (the "hype") of an article in the research community at large, based on the underlying citation network.
    Top 10%
    influence
    This indicator reflects the overall/total impact of an article in the research community at large, based on the underlying citation network (diachronically).
    Top 1%
    impulse
    This indicator reflects the initial momentum of an article directly after its publication, based on the underlying citation network.
    Top 10%
Powered by OpenAIRE graph
Found an issue? Give us feedback
citations
This is an alternative to the "Influence" indicator, which also reflects the overall/total impact of an article in the research community at large, based on the underlying citation network (diachronically).
BIP!Citations provided by BIP!
popularity
This indicator reflects the "current" impact/attention (the "hype") of an article in the research community at large, based on the underlying citation network.
BIP!Popularity provided by BIP!
influence
This indicator reflects the overall/total impact of an article in the research community at large, based on the underlying citation network (diachronically).
BIP!Influence provided by BIP!
impulse
This indicator reflects the initial momentum of an article directly after its publication, based on the underlying citation network.
BIP!Impulse provided by BIP!
131
Top 10%
Top 1%
Top 10%
bronze